Joseph Schumpeter, honderd jaar economische ontwikkeling -

€ 11,95
Envoi
Envoi pour € 2,95
90depuis 4 avr.. '23, 20:06
Partager via
ou

Caractéristiques

AuteurJan Boels
ConditieGelezen
Productnummer (ISBN)9789461591456

Description

BoekenBalie maakt van tweedehands jouw eerste keuze. Met een Trustscore van 4,8 (excellent) en 30 dagen retour garantie maken we dat iedere dag waar.

Titel: Joseph Schumpeter, honderd jaar economische ontwikkeling - historisch-theoretische beschouwing
Auteur: Jan Boels
ISBN: 9789461591456
Conditie: Goed

Economic development changed the world during the allpervasive industrial era.
Economic growth, technological progress, prosperity and welfare have undergone a
dramatic metamorphosis. The institutional impact of development may have been
even greater. The laissezfaire system and pioneer capitalism transformed since into
an institutionalized capitalism with a human face, with rules, values and a society as
a symbiosis of prosperity and general welfare – at least according to its idealized
image.
Joseph Schumpeter's pioneering work on economic development has been path
breaking in explaining the dramatic material progress, the substantial improvement
of the quality of life and the institutional impact, which have fundamentally chan
ged the image of Western societies. But until recently in standard economic theory
and the economic debates of the twentieth century, little or no attention was paid
to his ideas. His original notions of the organic structure of social society, or the
economic dynamics and interactions with noneconomic domains, were overlooked
or viewed with exaggerated scepticism through a neoclassical lens.
The twentieth century economy was dominated by neoclassical theory,
whether or not complementary with monetary or Keynesian views. In the
theoretical approach it was generally believed that equilibrium was central, and
only in the last decades were microeconomic dynamics reluctantly incorporated.
The neoclassical analysis based on abstract variables, causal relationships and
unambiguous axioms was diametrically opposed to nondeterministic and uncertain
economic dynamism. And the debate was dominated by the contradiction between
analytical and historical thinking.
The great merit of Schumpeter lies in his explanation of economic dynamism, by
which he succeeded in breaking out of the static and exact thinking mode. While
economic theory was indispensable for analysing the economic mechanism and
interpretation of economic equilibrium, it was unfit as an explanation for economic
dynamism. In the dynamic economy there is no longer an abstract image of causal
relationships, but a complex reality with frequent interactions, combined with
“tâtonnement” and uncertainty rather than unambiguous axioms. To his mind, the
theoretical approach should go hand in hand with the historical reflection and is
synthesis and not dichotomy central. The ideas of Schumpeter are inseparable from
his personal background and character. There is certainly a close link between the
scientist and Schumpeter the man. We see an erudite scientist who consistently
refers to a reality which is channelled through the creative human spirit.
230
He wants to capture a reality in a universal social science, with an economic sub
structure. Rejecting any need for formalism, he tries in his multifaceted approach to
constantly scan and enlarge his scientific horizon. He sees fixed patterns and deter
ministic models as rigid and abstract definitions of the complex reality that is con
stantly evolving. He is not afraid to outline very different aspects of reality, mainly
to provoke debate rather than to deliver unified theories.
In his quest for a universal social science, he appears lengthy and uncommitted,
in some cases at the expense of depth in his explanation of the economic
development process. As a result his theoretical elaborations, as when he describes
the underlying factors of the innovation process, miss the necessary depth, or are
deficient in their analytical explanation, as when the longterm waves are discussed.
His views on the dynamic economy, which knows no regularity in time or
character, are sensitive to the zeitgeist and to unpredictable changes. The economic
process occurs, in his view, in fits and starts and may in the course of time take
different forms and directions without a single based result. Over the course of time
his thinking is determined by the unique nature of history and less by a theoretical
look at a reduced reality. A preanalytical approach to a complex reality is the
premise for an objective analysis, with value judgments subsequently.
The great merit of Schumpeter lays in the fact that he broke through the
prevailing prejudices of the political economy of the nineteenth century and
disproved the prevailing neoclassical axioms of economic development theory.
Schumpeter’s vision which until recently was dismissed as a vague and esoteric
concept, now seems essential for the solution of the great issues of our time.
Despite his at times theoretical imperfection, Schumpeter with his original
thinking belongs to the great economic thinkers of the twentieth century.
A scientist who can no longer be dismissed as a footnote in history, as was the
case for many years, but now deserves respect.
In the late twentieth century Schumpeter became recognized for his work on the
economic development process, whereby he became very much associated with
innovation in the sense of 'new combinations' or 'creative destruction': a process
driven by creative and strongwilled entrepreneurs, pushing prosperity to ever
higher levels.
In the meantime, economic growth – until recently categorized in neoclassical
theory to the realm of ‘God and the engineers’ – has been increasingly identified
with technological progress.
Renewal and development is the essence of economic dynamism at the micro
level.
The driving mechanism of material progress is also the basis of general welfare.
Yet there are tensions between economic, social, ecological and institutional
aspects. Renewal and development, or the continuous qualitative improvement
231
instead of purely quantitative growth, as Schumpeter pointed, is an absolute neces
sity for a world in which the economic system through an unsustainable growth
path in the twentieth Century, has currently reached its limits. A growth path which
needs to be shifted in an economic sustainable fashion. To this end there needs to
be a shift from growth for development in terms of nature and the environment and
from material wealth to the welfare of man and world. And an adjustment of the
institutional framework to reduce perverse tendencies, including those evoked by
neoliberal ideology, ignorance or as a result of new media.
Schumpeter's contributions have for decades been dismissed as eclectic and
lacking in depth, or as mere ‘intelligent afterdinner talk’ in the eyes of leading
peers, such as Lord Robbins of the London School of Economics. This was not only
the result of his often rambling and noncommittal views, but perhaps also
motivated by an overreliance on English translations and versions of his later books,
which lacked exposure to his original ideas and thinking.
Analysis of his early German work is essential to understand the reasoning
behind his beliefs, as he strove to make a synthesis between the AngloSaxon
analytical approach and the continental historical approach. His overarching social
science total concept of the capitalist system – the essential contribution of
Schumpeter – remains as a result underexposed, and often disintegrates into
disjointed individual opinions of a stand alone nature.
Yet a glimpse at his collected works – Das Wesen und der Hauptinhalt der
theoretischen Nationalökonomie (1908), Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung
(1912, 1926), The Theory of Economic Development (1934), Business Cycles (1939)
and Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (1942) – gives an insight into his vision of
the relationships in economic events and the process of emergence, the
development and the possible collapse of capitalist civilization.
The posthumously published History of Economic Analysis (1954) finally, appears an
attempt to a final summary of his universal social science with an encyclopaedic
character.
The analysis of Schumpeter was proven correct in terms of economic
development, prosperity and institutional change – albeit less dramatically than the
perhaps honourable demise of the capitalist system as he imagined – but did not
bring forward barriers for indiscriminate growth and consumption, which up to the
1970s was not seen as relevant.
His views offer though a tool for addressing the major issues of our time,
focusing on the sustainability of the economic system. Or as Schumpeter already
said 100 years ago: “Economics based upon ‘new combinations’ ought to be a
continually selfreproducing system”.

Waarom je bij BoekenBalie moet zijn voor al je tweedehands boeken:

  • Bestel je voor 15:00 uur? Dan vliegt het dezelfde dag nog jouw kant op!
  • Meer dan 400.000 tweedehands boeken om uit te kiezen
  • We checken alle boeken eigenhandig
  • Vanaf 40 euro of bij 4 boeken is de verzending op onze rekening
  • 30 dagen retourgarantie


Numéro de l'annonce: a122429489